RECAP
We've now examined the five elements of the cycle of prosperity: technology, food supply, human capital, economic growth and wealth, and trade. We've noted that this cycle exists within two important societal environments. First is a physical environment, with its specific set of resources, challenges, and proximity to other societies. Second, a cultural environment shapes attitudes from notions of providence or fate to ideas about human relationships with the physical environment, values about human relationships, and perceptions of the ultimate purpose behind our existence. Regarding the European cultural environment, we've seen that those societies that would play a leading role in modern prosperity were deeply influenced by uniquely Judeo-Christian ideas of respecting individuals (and their property), linear time and progress, order and reason, and decentralization.
Before turning to the question of prosperity and the poorest people in the world today, I want to summarize what one scholar identifies as the four most critical factors that lead to prosperity in the modern world. Scholar William J. Bernstein identifies the following key issues in his book The Birth of Plenty: How the Prosperity of the Modern World Was Created.
- Property Rights
- Scientific Rationalism
- Capital Markets
- Technology and Infrastructure
(The next few posts are excerpts from essays I've previously written on this topic.)
PROPERTY RIGHTS
Without property rights and civil rights, little motivates the inventor or businessman to create and produce beyond his immediate need. (1)
Ancient World
Property rights refer to the ability of individuals to buy, sell and utilize goods with minimal or no interference from other players in society. It is not so much about the relationship between people and things as it is about the relationship between people concerning things. The one, truly significant example of property rights budding in the ancient world, was Greek Civilization during the middle portion of the first century B.C.E. Land was divided into small plots, decisions were made through democratic processes, and there was a highly egalitarian spirit among Greek citizens. Property rights were respected and institutionalized, but property primarily consisted of land. The population eventually grew to a point where the number of people exceeded the land to support them. The only option was to annex more land, but the Greek culture did not have conscription and could not form conquering armies without utterly transforming the very nature of their culture, and that is precisely what happened.
No other civilization, including Rome, ever approximated the kind of respect for property and civil rights the Greeks shared during those few centuries. William Bernstein notes that populist movements emerged in places here and there but never really took root. He points to the sabbath and Jubilee codes of the Old Testament as an exceptional vision of an egalitarian society in terms of individual and civil rights but rightly notes that there is no evidence that Israel ever abided by these codes.
European Middle Ages
With the collapse of the Roman Empire in the mid-first century, Europe dissolved into a myriad of feudal estates. Life became violent and dangerous. People gathered in communities and gave their allegiance to a lord in return for protection. The only unifying institution across Europe was the Church. The Church technically owned the land, and the feudal lord ruled a region on behalf of the Church. These lords eventually formed alliances with other lords installing regional rulers or kings.
Two factors acted as a check on the power of Kings and Queens. One was competition. If a King or Queen became too oppressive for the aristocracy, the aristocracy might unite in opposition or form alliances with their monarch's enemies. Second was the Church. The Church was the de facto bank of the time. Oppose the Church, and you might find yourself high and dry in a time of financial need. This is not to mention the power of the Church to excommunicate and inflict other punishments on rulers. Of course, the Church could also employ these measures against barons who rebelled against a ruler the Church favored. (2)
Magna Carta
Monarchs were required to pay an annual fee to the Church for the privilege of ruling. King John of England (1166-1216) rebelled against this idea but finally acceded after being excommunicated by the Pope. Shortly after, he embarked on a disastrous military campaign to take Normandy and ran out of funds. John engaged in a wide variety of injustices to collect the funds he needed from his subjects. The barons united against him, and John quickly faced a dilemma. He was hardly in the good graces of the Pope, and his barons were united against him. He was forced to make a deal.
The barons drew up a list of demands called the Magna Carta. They forced the King to acquiesce. The Magna Carta, signed in 1215, introduced such ideas as due process, trial by a jury, and taxation only with representation. Most notably, it made the King and the government subject not only to civil law (legislated law) but common law or being governed by time-honored traditions for ordering human affairs. This placed significant limitations on the King's ability to change laws arbitrarily. (3)
The Magna Carta did not come to full flower for at least another five hundred years. Kings resisted and challenged it at every turn, but over time, the Great Charter prevailed. Possibly contributing to its victory was the Plague in the middle of the fourteenth century. Approximately a third of Europe died in the Plague. The effect in England was that many aristocrats were left without sufficient labor to maintain their estates. The price of labor soared. Attempts to freeze wages and bind peasants to the estates failed. Many peasants prospered, and some assumed control over estates abandoned by the wealthy either because of death or bankruptcy. The Plague increased the number of people with an economic stake in society across Europe but especially in England. A more widely shared economic stake also meant a more widely shared determination to protect that stake.
Renaissance to Enlightenment
The progress of property rights was slow from the time of the Magna Carta to the seventeenth century. Over the centuries, the Magna Carta came to be taken for granted as the basis for the English government. The next significant leap came in the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries with Sir Edward Coke. Coke had been made a justice of the King's bench and eventually established an independent judiciary, grounding his case firmly in the Magna Carta. Everyone was subject to the law, from peasants to the King, for the first time. (4)
As the Reformation and the Counter-Reformation radically altered intellectual life in Europe, new thinkers arose, providing a more thoroughly developed rationale for property rights and liberal democracy. John Locke (1632-1704), Adam Smith (1723-1790), and Thomas Jefferson (1743-1826) are among some of the more notable contributors.
Another important innovation, evolving first in Italy and later in Holland and England, was the idea of the corporation. Corporations allowed for the amassing and investment of large sums of capital. The more important feature was the corporation's limited liability to individual investors. Investors were only liable for the amount they invested in a given enterprise. Creditors were prohibited from coming after personal assets when corporate enterprises failed. Similarly, debtor's prison was eventually abolished, removing a major obstacle to entrepreneurs taking business risks. It is one thing to lose your possessions in a business venture but quite another to lose your freedom. (5)
Another important innovation was the emergence of intellectual property rights like patents and copyrights. William Bernstein claims the first patent law was issued in Florence in 1474. (6) Evolving over time, intellectual property rights spurred innovation by ensuring inventors and other creative entrepreneurs that their often-arduous efforts would be financially rewarded. Without such rights, an inventor could spend years developing and perfecting a technology, only to have someone steal it and profit from it. Intellectual property rights guaranteed inventors the control and distribution of the technology they created for a fixed period. They could retain the use of patents for themselves or lease their use. This set off a wave of some of the most creative endeavors in the history of humanity and was one of the key ingredients of the Industrial Revolution.
Industrial Revolution and Beyond
William Bernstein points out that up until 1800, property was virtually synonymous with land. (13) Most commerce was primarily done by raising crops and livestock for consumption and trade—this required land. Certainly, there were other occupations, but they made up a small part of the total economy. The amassing of capital and its productive employment since the Eighteenth Century has changed all that. Land is now only a small part of the economy. Over the past two centuries, we have witnessed ever greater elaborations of property rights as the nature of property has radically changed.
Bernstein notes that there were three liberal democracies with the attendant respect for property rights in 1790: England, the United States of America, and Switzerland. By 1900 there were thirteen. Sixty years later, there were thirty-six. He estimated sixty-one in 1990. Despite occasional setbacks, the valuing and protection of property rights continue to expand across the globe. (14)
Why Property Rights Are Important
No economic system where property has been held in common has led to widespread, sustained prosperity. Within any human community, some will be more gifted at, or more willing to do, productive labor. Those who are less efficient and productive have no incentive to improve. They benefit at the expense of the more productive. More productive people receive no additional benefit for their better-than-average production and have no reason to be so productive. Productivity sinks to the level of the least productive members.
Private property rights make it much more probable that someone will receive just compensation for their work compared to others who do similar work. Risk takers are motivated to take greater risks because they can be assured they will reap the rewards of their efforts. Thieves or government entities will not deprive them of the new wealth they create. This seems so "ho-hum" to many of us today. Yet it is only within the last couple of centuries that entire societies could take such thinking for granted if they can now. Property rights have been at the core of the unprecedented prosperity of recent centuries.
(1) William J. Bernstein, The Birth of Plenty: How the Prosperity of the Modern World was Created, (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2004).
(2) Bernstein, 56.
(3) Bernstein, 71-73.
(4) Bernstein, 74-78.
(5) Bernstein, 149-156.
(6) Bernstein, 83.
(7) Bernstein, 90.
(8) Bernstein, 71.
Never mind that the European white man actually stole much of the land and the wealth, and the lives, from the natives in their former colonies al over the world.
It is now called "crown" land in Canada, New Zealand and Australia for instance.
They even used the law to steal land too. As in the case of Hawaii where the whiteys used their superior knowledge of the law to buy up most of the land. The natives Hawaii
were completely ignorant of how the law worked and of how they were being duped.
And didnt the white man steal, by a massive sustained exercise in SUPER GRAND THEFT the lands of the native "americans" in what is now the USA. And then they used what were essentially genocidal policies to get rid of the natives who were quite rightly resisting the theft of their lands.
Check out references under THE TRAIL OF TEARS on your google.
Plus the whiteys broke most of hundreds of treaties that were made with the natives. And that process of treaty breaking is still occuring.
Check out the superb Columbus and Other Cannibals by Jack Forbes for the heart-breaking truth about what actually happened---from the victims point of view.
A time for weeping.
Plus God IS Red by Vin Deloria Jr.
Plus for a superb revisionist history why not check out American Holocaust by David Stannard.
Posted by: Sue | Oct 14, 2008 at 10:50 PM
Sue, thanks for these obeservations.
In this series I'm merely skimming the top of some very broad themes that relate prosperity. I heartily agree with the historical accounts you are raising here. I'd add the following observations.
If you've ever read books like Diamond's "Guns, Germs, and Steel," then you know that this process of conquering, dehumanizing, and displacing others has been the standard human behavior throughout history. Many of the peoples Whites displaced in America were people who had previously displaced other native Americans. (ex. Aztecs had conquered their region less than 200 years before the Spaniards arrived.) So I'm less inclined to attribute this domineering quality to being White and more inclined to attribute it to being human. People with inordinate power tend to use irresponsibly. Whites have been the latest in a long line of elitists.
But what is unique about European culture is that the idea of each person being in the "image of God" has never been far below the surface. (See my earlier post in this series, "Respect for the Individual.") As European explorers began to encounter Africans and peoples of the "New World" they justified slavery on the grounds that these people were uncivilized and sub-human. The Popes beginning in the 1400s denounced this interpretation and practice but were without the political clout to prevail against such efforts. From the beginning, there were always at least a minority of Christians who acted on the impulse that others were created in the image of God just as they were. Over the centuries their view has won the day either through explicit Christian efforts or secular humanist efforts whose conception of the value of the individual is inescapably bound to the Judeo-Christian heritage.
In some ways, your comment is making my point. Had Whites honored others equal human beings and respected property rights it would have checked their domineering ambitions.
Britain had the largest Empire. Historical economists note that resources coming in from the colonies, and goods shipped out to the colonies, never made up more than 5-10% of England's economy. Yet a tremendous amount of resources were spent to control the colonies and suppress any local economic development that would challenge British production. Economist conclude that not only was such action morally unjustifiable it was economically unjustifiable as well. Had the Brits engaged in trade and allowed industry to flourish elsewhere, both Britain and others would have been far better off.
Posted by: Michael W. Kruse | Oct 15, 2008 at 11:21 AM